Prosecuting Cartels without Direct Evidence 2006



Documents pareils
First Nations Assessment Inspection Regulations. Règlement sur l inspection aux fins d évaluation foncière des premières nations CONSOLIDATION

Application Form/ Formulaire de demande

COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION. Brussels, 18 September 2008 (19.09) (OR. fr) 13156/08 LIMITE PI 53

Public and European Business Law - Droit public et européen des affaires. Master I Law Level

Credit Note and Debit Note Information (GST/ HST) Regulations

Natixis Asset Management Response to the European Commission Green Paper on shadow banking

Règlement sur le télémarketing et les centres d'appel. Call Centres Telemarketing Sales Regulation

PIB : Définition : mesure de l activité économique réalisée à l échelle d une nation sur une période donnée.

Cheque Holding Policy Disclosure (Banks) Regulations. Règlement sur la communication de la politique de retenue de chèques (banques) CONSOLIDATION

Small Businesses support Senator Ringuette s bill to limit credit card acceptance fees

RULE 5 - SERVICE OF DOCUMENTS RÈGLE 5 SIGNIFICATION DE DOCUMENTS. Rule 5 / Règle 5

APPENDIX 2. Provisions to be included in the contract between the Provider and the. Holder

Calculation of Interest Regulations. Règlement sur le calcul des intérêts CONSOLIDATION CODIFICATION. Current to August 4, 2015 À jour au 4 août 2015

IPSAS 32 «Service concession arrangements» (SCA) Marie-Pierre Cordier Baudouin Griton, IPSAS Board

Support Orders and Support Provisions (Banks and Authorized Foreign Banks) Regulations

AUDIT COMMITTEE: TERMS OF REFERENCE

Name Use (Affiliates of Banks or Bank Holding Companies) Regulations

Discours du Ministre Tassarajen Pillay Chedumbrum. Ministre des Technologies de l'information et de la Communication (TIC) Worshop on Dot.

Improving the breakdown of the Central Credit Register data by category of enterprises

Forthcoming Database

CONTINUING CONSOLIDATION OF STATUTES ACT LOI SUR LA CODIFICATION PERMANENTE DES LOIS. 1 In this Act,

LE FORMAT DES RAPPORTS DU PERSONNEL DES COMMISSIONS DE DISTRICT D AMENAGEMENT FORMAT OF DISTRICT PLANNING COMMISSION STAFF REPORTS

Archived Content. Contenu archivé

Exemple PLS avec SAS

Comprendre l impact de l utilisation des réseaux sociaux en entreprise SYNTHESE DES RESULTATS : EUROPE ET FRANCE

Les contraintes de financement des PME en Afrique : le rôle des registres de crédit

Form of Deeds Relating to Certain Successions of Cree and Naskapi Beneficiaries Regulations

Export Permit (Steel Monitoring) Regulations. Règlement sur les licences d exportation (surveillance de l acier) CONSOLIDATION CODIFICATION

INDIVIDUALS AND LEGAL ENTITIES: If the dividends have not been paid yet, you may be eligible for the simplified procedure.

Loi sur l aide financière à la Banque Commerciale du Canada. Canadian Commercial Bank Financial Assistance Act CODIFICATION CONSOLIDATION

INVESTMENT REGULATIONS R In force October 1, RÈGLEMENT SUR LES INVESTISSEMENTS R En vigueur le 1 er octobre 2001

POSITION DESCRIPTION DESCRIPTION DE TRAVAIL

Disclosure on Account Opening by Telephone Request (Trust and Loan Companies) Regulations

AMENDMENT TO BILL 32 AMENDEMENT AU PROJET DE LOI 32

Input Tax Credit Information (GST/HST) Regulations

Paxton. ins Net2 desktop reader USB

APPENDIX 6 BONUS RING FORMAT

NORME INTERNATIONALE INTERNATIONAL STANDARD. Dispositifs à semiconducteurs Dispositifs discrets. Semiconductor devices Discrete devices

Interest Rate for Customs Purposes Regulations. Règlement sur le taux d intérêt aux fins des douanes CONSOLIDATION CODIFICATION

Disclosure on Account Opening by Telephone Request (Retail Associations) Regulations

BNP Paribas Personal Finance

Règlement relatif à l examen fait conformément à la Déclaration canadienne des droits. Canadian Bill of Rights Examination Regulations CODIFICATION

that the child(ren) was/were in need of protection under Part III of the Child and Family Services Act, and the court made an order on

C H A P T E R 4 C H A P I T R E 4. (Assented to June 16, 2011) (Date de sanction : 16 juin 2011)

Sub-Saharan African G-WADI

PRACTICE DIRECTION ON THE LENGTH OF BRIEFS AND MOTIONS ON APPEAL

CEPF FINAL PROJECT COMPLETION REPORT

Import Allocation Regulations. Règlement sur les autorisations d importation CONSOLIDATION CODIFICATION

Règlement sur les baux visés à la Loi no 1 de 1977 portant affectation de crédits. Appropriation Act No. 1, 1977, Leasing Regulations CODIFICATION

Eléments de statistique

Working Group on Implementation of UNGCP Meeting

Practice Direction. Class Proceedings

How to Login to Career Page

Instructions Mozilla Thunderbird Page 1

BILL C-452 PROJET DE LOI C-452 C-452 C-452 HOUSE OF COMMONS OF CANADA CHAMBRE DES COMMUNES DU CANADA

Panorama des bonnes pratiques de reporting «corruption»

Mon Service Public - Case study and Mapping to SAML/Liberty specifications. Gaël Gourmelen - France Telecom 23/04/2007

Quatre axes au service de la performance et des mutations Four lines serve the performance and changes

Marie Curie Individual Fellowships. Jean Provost Marie Curie Postdoctoral Fellow, Institut Langevin, ESCPI, INSERM, France

Railway Operating Certificate Regulations. Règlement sur les certificats d exploitation de chemin de fer CODIFICATION CONSOLIDATION

English Q&A #1 Braille Services Requirement PPTC Q1. Would you like our proposal to be shipped or do you prefer an electronic submission?

LOI SUR LE PROGRAMME DE TRAVAUX COMPENSATOIRES L.R.T.N.-O. 1988, ch. F-5. FINE OPTION ACT R.S.N.W.T. 1988,c.F-5

OFFICIAL STATUS OF CONSOLIDATIONS CARACTÈRE OFFICIEL DES CODIFICATIONS

Deadline(s): Assignment: in week 8 of block C Exam: in week 7 (oral exam) and in the exam week (written exam) of block D

Bill 204 Projet de loi 204

Nouveautés printemps 2013

Air Transportation Tax Order, Décret de 1995 sur la taxe de transport aérien CONSOLIDATION CODIFICATION

EU- Luxemburg- WHO Universal Health Coverage Partnership:

INTERNATIONAL CRIMINAL COURT. Article 98 TREATIES AND OTHER INTERNATIONAL ACTS SERIES Agreement between the UNITED STATES OF AMERICA and GABON

Préconisations pour une gouvernance efficace de la Manche. Pathways for effective governance of the English Channel

DOCUMENTATION - FRANCAIS... 2

EN UNE PAGE PLAN STRATÉGIQUE

UML : Unified Modeling Language

SMALL CITY COMMERCE (EL PEQUEÑO COMERCIO DE LAS PEQUEÑAS CIUDADES)

Life Companies Borrowing Regulations. Règlement sur les emprunts des sociétés d assurance-vie CONSOLIDATION CODIFICATION

RÉSUMÉ DE THÈSE. L implantation des systèmes d'information (SI) organisationnels demeure une tâche difficile

OUVRIR UN COMPTE CLIENT PRIVÉ

For the attention of all Delegations/ A l attention de toutes les Délégations

Tier 1 / Tier 2 relations: Are the roles changing?

The new consumables catalogue from Medisoft is now updated. Please discover this full overview of all our consumables available to you.

LOI SUR LE RÉGIME D ASSURANCE COLLECTIVE DE LA FONCTION PUBLIQUE PUBLIC SERVICE GROUP INSURANCE BENEFIT PLAN ACT

THÈSE. présentée à TÉLÉCOM PARISTECH. pour obtenir le grade de. DOCTEUR de TÉLÉCOM PARISTECH. Mention Informatique et Réseaux. par.

Présentation par François Keller Fondateur et président de l Institut suisse de brainworking et M. Enga Luye, CEO Belair Biotech

DOCUMENTATION - FRANCAIS... 2

Projet de réorganisation des activités de T-Systems France

FÉDÉRATION INTERNATIONALE DE NATATION Diving

Consultation Report / Rapport de consultation REGDOC-2.3.3, Periodic Safety Reviews / Bilans périodiques de la sûreté

Editing and managing Systems engineering processes at Snecma

Lean approach on production lines Oct 9, 2014

Below are the answers to question(s) submitted in regards to the above noted RFP as of August 5 th, 2014

accidents and repairs:

Ships Elevator Regulations. Règlement sur les ascenseurs de navires CODIFICATION CONSOLIDATION. C.R.C., c C.R.C., ch. 1482

Nordion Europe S.A. Incorporation Authorization Order. Décret autorisant la constitution de Nordion Europe S.A. CONSOLIDATION CODIFICATION

Bill 12 Projet de loi 12

Borrowing (Property and Casualty Companies and Marine Companies) Regulations

Emergency Management Act. Loi sur la gestion des urgences CODIFICATION CONSOLIDATION. S.C. 2007, c. 15 L.C. 2007, ch. 15. À jour au 4 août 2015

THE LAW SOCIETY OF UPPER CANADA BY-LAW 19 [HANDLING OF MONEY AND OTHER PROPERTY] MOTION TO BE MOVED AT THE MEETING OF CONVOCATION ON JANUARY 24, 2002

donor which means an individual person who makes a charitable contribution to The Playhouse or one of its Clients;

Consultants en coûts - Cost Consultants

Gestion des prestations Volontaire

Transcription:

Prosecuting Cartels without Direct Evidence 2006 The OECD Global Forum on Competition debated prosecuting cartels without evidence of agreement in February 2006. This document includes an executive summary and the documents from the meeting: an analytical note by Mr. John Clark for the OECD, written submissions from Algeria, Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Croatia, the Czech Republic, Estonia, the European Commission, France, Jamaica, Japan, Korea, Lithuania, Romania, the Russian Federation, Switzerland, Chinese Taipei, Turkey, the United States, Zambia, and BIAC, as well as an aide-memoire of the discussion. Circumstantial evidence is employed in cartel cases in all countries. The better practice is to use circumstantial evidence holistically, giving it cumulative effect, rather than on an item-by-item basis. Complicating the use of circumstantial evidence are provisions in national competition laws that variously define the nature of agreements that are subject to the law. There are two general types of circumstantial evidence: communication evidence and economic evidence. Of the two, communication evidence is considered to be the more important. Economic evidence is almost always ambiguous. It could be consistent with either agreement or independent action. Therefore it requires careful analysis. National treatment of cartels, such as whether they are prosecuted as crimes or as administrative violations, can affect the burden of proof that applies to the cases, and hence the use of circumstantial evidence. It can be difficult to convince courts to accept circumstantial evidence in cartel cases, especially where the potential liability for having violated the anti-cartel provisions of the competition law is high. There are circumstances in countries that are relatively new to anti-cartel enforcement that could affect the extent to which they rely on circumstantial evidence in their cases. Best Practices for the Formal Exchange of Information between Competition Authorities in Hard Core Cartel Investigations (2005) Hard Core Cartels: Third Report on the Implementation of the 1998 Recommendation (2005) Hard Core Cartels: Recent Progress and Challenges Ahead (2003) Fighting Hard Core Cartels: Harm, Effective Sanctions and Leniency Programmes (2002) Recommendation of the Council concerning Effective Action against Hard Core Cartels (1998)

Unclassified DAF/COMP/GF(2006)7 DAF/COMP/GF(2006)7 Unclassified Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Economiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 11-Sep-2006 English/French DIRECTORATE FOR FINANCIAL AND ENTERPRISE AFFAIRS COMPETITION COMMITTEE Global Forum on Competition Cancels & replaces the same document of 29 May 2006 PROSECUTING CARTELS WITHOUT DIRECT EVIDENCE OF AGREEMENT English/French JT03213324 Document complet disponible sur OLIS dans son format d'origine Complete document available on OLIS in its original format

FOREWORD This document comprises proceedings in the original language of a Roundtable on Prosecuting Cartels without Direct Evidence of Agreement which was held at the Global Forum on Competition in February 2006. It is published under the responsibility of the Secretary General of the OECD to bring information on this topic to the attention of a wider audience. This compilation is one of a series of publications entitled "Competition Policy Roundtables". PRÉFACE Ce document rassemble la documentation, dans la langue originale dans laquelle elle a été soumise, relative à une table ronde sur les poursuites contre les ententes en l'absence de preuves directes, qui s'est tenue lors du Forum Mondial sur la Concurrence en février 2006. Il est publié sous la responsabilité du Secrétaire général de l'ocde, afin de porter à la connaissance d'un large public les éléments d'information qui ont été réunis à cette occasion. Cette compilation fait partie de la série intitulée "Les tables rondes sur la politique de la concurrence". Visit our Internet Site Consultez notre site Internet http://www.oecd.org/competition 2

OTHER TITLES SERIES ROUNDTABLES ON COMPETITION POLICY 1. Competition Policy and Environment OCDE/GD(96)22 2. Failing Firm Defence OCDE/GD(96)23 3. Competition Policy and Film Distribution OCDE/GD(96)60 4. Competition Policy and Efficiency Claims in Horizontal Agreements OCDE/GD(96)65 5. The Essential Facilities Concept OCDE/GD(96)113 6. Competition in Telecommunications OCDE/GD(96)114 7. The Reform of International Satellite Organisations OCDE/GD(96)123 8. Abuse of Dominance and Monopolisation OCDE/GD(96)131 9. Application of Competition Policy to High Tech Markets OCDE/GD(97)44 10. General Cartel Bans: Criteria for Exemption for Small and Medium-sized Enterprises OCDE/GD(97)53 11. Competition Issues related to Sports OCDE/GD(97)128 12. Application of Competition Policy to the Electricity Sector OCDE/GD(97)132 13. Judicial Enforcement of Competition Law OCDE/GD(97)200 14. Resale Price Maintenance OCDE/GD(97)229 15. Railways: Structure, Regulation and Competition Policy DAFFE/CLP(98)1 16. Competition Policy and International Airport Services DAFFE/CLP(98)3 17. Enhancing the Role of Competition in the Regulation of Banks DAFFE/CLP(98)16 18. Competition Policy and Intellectual Property Rights DAFFE/CLP(98)18 19. Competition and Related Regulation Issues in the Insurance Industry DAFFE/CLP(98)20 20. Competition Policy and Procurement Markets DAFFE/CLP(99)3 21. Regulation and Competition Issues in Broadcasting in the light of Convergence DAFFE/CLP(99)1 3

22. Relationship between Regulators and Competition Authorities DAFFE/CLP(99)8 23. Buying Power of Multiproduct Retailers DAFFE/CLP(99)21 24. Promoting Competition in Postal Services DAFFE/CLP(99)22 25. Oligopoly DAFFE/CLP(99)25 26. Airline Mergers and Alliances DAFFE/CLP(2000)1 27. Competition in Professional Services DAFFE/CLP(2000)2 28. Competition in Local Services DAFFE/CLP(2000)13 29. Mergers in Financial Services DAFFE/CLP(2000)17 30. Promoting Competition in the Natural Gas Industry DAFFE/CLP(2000)18 31. Competition Issues in Electronic Commerce DAFFE/CLP(2000)32 32. Competition and Regulation Issues in the Pharmaceutical Industry DAFFE/CLP(2000)29 33. Competition Issues in Joint Ventures DAFFE/CLP(2000)33 34. Competition Issues in Road Transport DAFFE/CLP(2001)10 35. Price Transparency DAFFE/CLP(2001)22 36. Competition Policy in Subsidies and State Aid DAFFE/CLP(2001)24 37. Portfolio Effects in Conglomerate Mergers DAFFE/COMP(2002)5 38. Competition and Regulation Issues in Telecommunications DAFFE/COMP(2002)6 39. Merger Review in Emerging High Innovation Markets DAFFE/COMP(2002)20 40. Loyalty and Fidelity Discounts and Rebates DAFFE/COMP(2002)21 41. Communication by Competition Authorities DAFFE/COMP(2003)4 42. Substantive Criteria used for the Assessment of Mergers DAFFE/COMP(2003)5 43. Competition Issues in the Electricity Sector DAFFE/COMP(2003)14 44. Media Mergers DAFFE/COMP(2003)16 45. Non Commercial Services Obligations and Liberalisation DAFFE/COMP(2004)19 46. Competition and Regulation in the Water Sector DAFFE/COMP(2004)20 47. Regulating Market Activities by Public Sector DAFFE/COMP(2004)36 4

48. Merger Remedies DAF/COMP(2004)21 49. Cartels: Sanctions against Individuals DAF/COMP(2004)39 50. Intellectual Property Rights DAF/COMP(2004)24 51. Predatory Foreclosure DAF/COMP(2005)14 52. Competition and Regulation in Agriculture: Monopsony Buying and Joint Selling DAF/COMP(2005)44 53. Enhancing Beneficial Competition in the Health Professions DAF/COMP(2005)45 54. Evaluation of the Actions and Resources of Competition Authorities DAF/COMP(2005)30 55. Structural Reform in the Rail Industry DAF/COMP(2005)46 56. Competition on the Merits DAF/COMP(2005)27 57. Resale Below Cost Laws and Regulations DAF/COMP(2005)43 58. Barriers to Entry DAF/COMP(2005)42 5

6

TABLE OF CONTENTS EXECUTIVE SUMMARY... 9 SYNTHÈSE... 13 BACKGROUND NOTE... 17 NOTE DE RÉFÉRENCE... 43 NATIONAL CONTRIBUTIONS Algeria... 73 Argentina... 79 Brazil... 83 Chile... 87 Croatia... 91 Czech Republic... 101 Estonia... 109 European Commission... 111 France... 119 Jamaica... 123 Japan... 127 Korea... 135 Lithuania... 145 Romania... 151 Russian Federation... 155 Switzerland... 159 Chinese Taipei... 163 Turkey... 169 United States... 173 Zambia... 179 BIAC... 187 SUMMARY OF THE DISCUSSION... 193 COMPTE RENDU DE LA DISCUSSION... 203 7

8

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY by the Secretariat Considering the discussion at the roundtable, the delegates written submissions and the Secretariat s background paper, several key points emerge: 1. Circumstantial evidence is employed in cartel cases in all countries. Competition law enforcement officials always strive to obtain direct evidence of agreement in prosecuting cartel cases, but sometimes it is not available. Cartel operators conceal their activities and usually they do not co-operate with an investigation of their conduct, unless they perceive that it is to their advantage to participate in a leniency programme. In this context, circumstantial evidence can be important. Almost every country making a written or oral contribution to the roundtable described at least one case in which circumstantial evidence was used to significant effect. At the same time, there are limits to the use of circumstantial evidence. Such evidence, especially economic evidence, can be ambiguous. It must be interpreted correctly by investigators, competition agencies and courts. Importantly, circumstantial evidence can be, and often is, used together with direct evidence. 2. The better practice is to use circumstantial evidence holistically, giving its cumulative effect, rather than on an item-by-item basis. One delegate described the methodology for evaluating circumstantial evidence as like an impressionist painting, comprising many dots or brush strokes which together form an image. Another likened the process to a jig-saw puzzle. In this way, circumstantial evidence, which by definition does not describe the specific terms of an agreement, can be better understood. The materials submitted for the roundtable described a few cases in which courts declined to use this holistic approach, requiring instead that each item of evidence be linked directly to a specific agreement. The result was that the cases failed. Of course, given the ambiguous nature of some circumstantial evidence, the holistic approach can result in errors. Business representatives urged that no case be based solely on circumstantial evidence, given the significant liability facing businesses that are found to have participated in a cartel. It did not appear that any other delegation embraced this position. On balance, the holistic approach is much preferable to a requirement that each item of circumstantial be linked directly to a specific agreement. 3. Complicating the use of circumstantial evidence are provisions in national competition laws that variously define the nature of agreements that are subject to the law. The anti-cartel provisions of all competition laws apply to more than straightforward explicit agreements. Laws use such terms as concerted practice, understanding and arrangement. When evaluating an evidentiary record, the nature of the agreement to which it applies may not be fully clear. This issue arises in the context of facilitating practices. These are practices, such as information exchanges, which can facilitate an underlying cartel agreement. Evidence of them is circumstantial evidence of a cartel agreement, but it is probably not sufficient by itself to prove such an agreement. In some countries, courts have separately evaluated facilitating 9

practices for their anticompetitive effect. In others, however, an underlying cartel agreement must be shown. In other respects, it seems that in most countries the evidentiary burden facing the law enforcement agency does not vary according to whether the conduct is considered to be an agreement or some other kind of concerted action described in the law. 4. There are two general types of circumstantial evidence: communication evidence and economic evidence. Of the two, communication evidence is considered to be the more important. Communication evidence is evidence that cartel operators met or otherwise communicated, but does not describe the substance of their communications. It includes, for example, records of telephone conversations among suspected cartel participants, of their travel to a common destination and notes or records of meetings in which they participated. Communication evidence can be highly probative of an agreement. Almost all of the circumstantial cases described by delegations included communication evidence; in some the evidence was compelling. 5. Economic evidence is almost always ambiguous. It could be consistent with either agreement or independent action. Therefore it requires careful analysis. Economic evidence can be categorized as either conduct or structural evidence. The former includes, most importantly, evidence of parallel conduct by suspected cartel members, e.g., simultaneous and identical price increases or suspicious bidding patterns in public tenders. It can also include evidence of facilitating practices, though that conduct could also be characterised as quasi-communication evidence. Structural economic evidence includes evidence of such factors as high market concentration and homogeneous products. Of these two types of economic evidence, conduct evidence is considered the more important. Economic evidence must be carefully evaluated. The evidence should be inconsistent with the hypothesis that the market participants are acting unilaterally in their self interest. Economics, including the use of game theory, can be instructive on how to make this judgment. It appears that in most countries, however, that kind of analysis is not yet employed. But further, economic evidence can play an important role in the initial stages of a cartel investigation. A proper analysis of it could provide a basis for deciding which of several possible cases are likely to be the most fruitful to pursue, with the hope and expectation that better evidence of agreement, both direct and circumstantial, will be discovered. 6. National treatment of cartels, such as whether they are prosecuted as crimes or as administrative violations, can affect the burden of proof that applies to the cases, and hence the use of circumstantial evidence. In most countries, cartels (and other violations of the competition law) are prosecuted administratively. The principle administrative sanctions applied to this conduct are fines, usually only assessed against organisations but sometimes against natural persons, and remedial orders. In a minority of countries, but a growing one, cartels are prosecuted criminally. In most instances the burden of proof facing the competition agency is higher in a criminal case. The result is that it is usually more important that direct evidence of agreement be generated in these cases. The United States has long used the criminal process in the cartel cases prosecuted by the government, and virtually all of its cases are built on direct evidence. Still, circumstantial evidence is admissible, and useful, in that country and elsewhere. 10

7. It can be difficult to convince courts to accept circumstantial evidence in cartel cases, especially where the potential liability for having violated the anti-cartel provisions of the competition law is high. A few jurisdictions in which there has been judicial review of decisions by competition agencies in cartel cases reported that courts sometimes view cases built on circumstantial evidence with scepticism. In this regard, as more cases are appealed to courts, the standards that they apply to circumstantial evidence are continuing to evolve. Hopefully, courts will come to see that circumstantial evidence subjected to sound economic analysis and viewed holistically can be highly probative. 8. There are circumstances in countries that are relatively new to anti-cartel enforcement that could affect the extent to which they rely on circumstantial evidence in their cases. A country just beginning to enforce its competition law may face obstacles in obtaining direct evidence of a cartel agreement. It probably will not have in place an effective leniency programme, which is a primary source of direct evidence. There may be lacking in the country a strong competition culture, which could make it more difficult for the competition agency to generate co-operation with its anti-cartel programme. In short, the competition agency could have relatively greater difficulty in generating direct evidence in its cartel cases, which would imply that it will have to rely more heavily on circumstantial evidence. A few delegations confirmed that this is the situation in their countries. But there is a countervailing phenomenon: the relatively high incidence in these countries of naïve cartels cartels in which their members do not attempt to conceal their activity, either because they are unaware that their conduct is unlawful or because they are not sufficiently sophisticated to do so. In the case of naïve cartels direct evidence is relatively plentiful, rendering circumstantial evidence less important. Another point was made by a few countries in which cartels were prosecuted as crimes initially under their new competition laws. It seemed that the higher burden of proof associated with criminal prosecution made the competition agency s anti-cartel burden more difficult. The advice from these countries was to begin administratively, perhaps later moving to criminal prosecution. Finally, there was general agreement in the discussion that a strong competition culture is an essential component of a successful anti-cartel programme. Education and public persuasion are important means of developing such a culture, but an even better one is vigorous enforcement of the law. The competition agency should strive to generate good cartel cases in important sectors, supported by strong evidence and demonstrating the benefits to consumers of effective anti-cartel enforcement. 11

12

SYNTHÈSE par le Secrétariat L analyse des discussions, au cours de la table ronde, des soumissions écrites des délégués et du document général du Secrétariat met en lumière plusieurs aspects essentiels : 1. Tous les pays utilisent des preuves indirectes dans les affaires d entente. Les autorités chargées d appliquer la législation sur la concurrence s efforcent d obtenir des preuves directes dans les affaires d entente, mais elles ne sont pas toujours disponibles. Les participants à des ententes dissimulent leurs activités et refusent en général de coopérer avec les enquêteurs, à moins qu ils ne perçoivent un avantage à le faire dans le cadre d un programme de clémence. Dans ce contexte, les preuves indirectes peuvent être importantes. Presque tous les pays qui ont apporté une contribution écrite ou orale à la table ronde ont décrit au moins un procès dans lequel des preuves indirectes ont été utilisées de manière significative. Dans le même temps, l utilisation de preuves indirectes se heurte à des limites. Ces preuves, notamment celles de nature économique, peuvent être ambiguës. Elles doivent être interprétées correctement par les enquêteurs, les autorités de la concurrence et les tribunaux. Surtout, elles peuvent être employées de concert avec des preuves directes, ce qui est souvent le cas. 2. La meilleure pratique consiste à utiliser des preuves indirectes dans une perspective d ensemble, plutôt que sur une base individuelle. Un délégué a comparé la méthode d évaluation des preuves indirectes à une peinture impressionniste, composée de multiples traits ou coups de pinceau qui forment ensemble une image. Un autre a assimilé le processus à un puzzle. Ces analogies permettent de mieux comprendre la nature des preuves indirectes, qui par définition ne décrivent pas les termes spécifiques d un accord. Les éléments fournis pour la table ronde présentaient certaines affaires dans lesquelles les tribunaux ont refusé de suivre cette approche globale, exigeant au contraire que chaque élément probant soit lié directement à un accord spécifique. Cette approche s est soldée par un échec. Certes, l approche globale peut générer des erreurs compte tenu de la nature ambiguë de certaines preuves indirectes. Les représentants des milieux d'affaires ont demandé qu aucune affaire ne soit instruite uniquement sur la base de preuves indirectes, eu égard à la responsabilité considérable à laquelle s exposent les entreprises reconnues coupables d avoir participé à une entente. Aucune autre délégation ne semble s être ralliée à cette position. Tout compte fait, l'approche holistique est nettement préférable à une obligation de relier directement à un accord spécifique chaque élément de preuve indirecte. 3. Les législations nationales sur la concurrence contiennent des dispositions qui compliquent l utilisation de preuves indirectes car elles ne donnent pas toute la même définition de la nature des «accords» soumis à la loi. Les dispositions contre les ententes de toutes les législations sur la concurrence s appliquent à des accords de nature très explicite. Les textes législatifs emploient des termes tels que «pratique concertée», «entente» et «arrangement». Lorsqu on évalue un recueil de preuves, la nature de l accord auquel il s applique n est pas forcément très claire. Ce problème survient dans le 13

contexte des «pratiques de facilitation». Ce sont des pratiques, comme l échange d informations, susceptibles de faciliter la conclusion d une entente. De telles pratiques constituent une preuve indirecte d une entente, mais ne seront probablement pas suffisantes pour prouver son existence. Dans certains pays, les tribunaux examinent séparément les pratiques de facilitation pour déterminer leur effet anticoncurrentiel. Dans d autres, l existence d une entente sous-jacente doit être prouvée. Il semble que dans la plupart des pays, la charge de la preuve qui incombe à l autorité chargée de faire appliquer la loi soit la même, que la conduite soit considérée comme un «accord» ou comme une autre forme d action concertée décrite dans la loi. 4. Il existe deux catégories générales de preuves indirectes : celles fondées sur une communication et celles de nature économique. Des deux, les preuves fondées sur une communication sont considérées comme les plus importantes. Les preuves fondées sur une communication attestent que les participants d une entente se sont rencontrés ou ont communiqué entre eux d une autre manière, mais ne décrivent pas sur quoi les propos ont porté. Il peut s agir d enregistrements de conversations téléphoniques entre des membres suspectés d une entente, d un déplacement qu ils ont effectués vers une destination commune, de notes ou de comptes rendus de réunions auxquelles ils ont participé. De tels indices peuvent receler une très forte valeur probante de l existence d un accord. Pratiquement tous les indices indirects décrits par les délégués incluaient des preuves fondées sur une communication ; dans certains cas, ces indices étaient confondants. 5. Les preuves de nature économique sont presque toujours ambiguës. Elles peuvent corroborer l existence d une entente comme celle d une action indépendante. C est pourquoi une analyse détaillée est de mise. Les preuves économiques se divisent en preuves de comportement ou preuves structurelles. Les premières incluent surtout les indices d agissements parallèles de la part des membres suspectés de l entente, par exemple des augmentations simultanées et identiques des prix ou des caractéristiques de soumission suspectes dans des appels d offres publics. Elles peuvent également inclure des indices de pratiques de nature à faciliter les ententes, bien qu un tel comportement puisse également être qualifié de «preuve de quasi-communication». Les preuves économiques de nature structurelle incluent des indices tels qu une forte concentration du marché et des produits homogènes. De ces deux types de preuves économiques, celles ayant trait au comportement sont les plus importantes. Les preuves économiques doivent être évaluées attentivement. Elles doivent démentir l hypothèse selon laquelle les participants du marché agissent de façon unilatérale et dans leur propre intérêt. Les indices économiques, qui font intervenir la théorie des jeux, peuvent éclairer sur la manière de parvenir à un tel jugement. Toutefois, il semble que dans la plupart des pays, ce type d analyse n est pas employé. En outre, les preuves économiques peuvent jouer un rôle important dans les phases initiales d une enquête sur une entente. Une analyse approfondie de ces preuves devrait fournir la base permettant de décider, parmi les affaires possibles, celles dans lesquelles des poursuites ont le plus de chances d aboutir, avec l espoir de découvrir des éléments probants plus convaincants, tant directs qu indirects, de l existence d un accord. 14

6. Le traitement national des ententes, considérées comme un délit pénal ou une infraction administrative, peut influer sur la charge de la preuve qui s applique à l affaire, et donc sur l utilisation des preuves indirectes. Dans la plupart des pays, les ententes (et autres violations de la législation sur la concurrence) font l objet de poursuites administratives. Les principales sanctions administratives prévues dans ces affaires sont des amendes, généralement infligées à l encontre d organisations mais parfois aussi contre des personnes physiques, et les ordonnances correctives. Dans une minorité de pays, dont le nombre va toutefois croissant, les ententes font l objet de poursuites pénales. Le plus souvent, la charge de la preuve qui incombe à l autorité de la concurrence est plus lourde dans une affaire pénale. Il s ensuit que, dans ces affaires, mieux vaut produire des preuves directes de l existence d un accord. Les États-Unis ont longtemps eu recours aux procédures pénales dans les affaires d entente instruites par le gouvernement, et pratiquement tous les procès s appuient sur des preuves directes. Les preuves indirectes sont néanmoins admissibles, et utiles, dans ce pays comme ailleurs. 7. Il peut être difficile de convaincre les tribunaux d accepter des preuves indirectes dans des affaires d entente, surtout lorsque la responsabilité potentielle liée à la violation de dispositions prohibant les ententes contenues dans la législation sur la concurrence est élevée. Quelques juridictions dans lesquelles les décisions prises par les autorités de la concurrence dans des affaires d entente ont fait l objet d un examen judiciaire ont fait savoir que les tribunaux considèrent parfois avec scepticisme les dossiers basés sur des preuves indirectes. À cet égard, les normes appliquées par les tribunaux en matière de preuves indirectes continuent d évoluer, car le nombre d affaires soumis à leur jugement augmente. Il faut espérer que les tribunaux en viendront à se rendre compte que la preuve indirecte qui fait l'objet d'une analyse de caractère économique et holistique peut être considérée comme étant une preuve évidente. 8. Dans les pays dans lesquels l application de la législation contre les ententes est relativement récente, certaines circonstances peuvent influer sur la confiance accordée aux preuves indirectes. Un pays qui commence tout juste à appliquer sa législation sur la concurrence peut se heurter à des obstacles pour réunir des preuves directes d une entente. Il ne disposera probablement pas d un programme de clémence qui constitue la source principale de preuves directes. La culture de la concurrence y sera vraisemblablement peu développée, ce qui compliquera les efforts de l autorité de la concurrence pour instaurer une coopération avec son programme de lutte contre les ententes. En résumé, l autorité de la concurrence pourrait rencontrer plus de difficultés à réunir des preuves directes dans les affaires d entente, ce qui l incitera à s en remettre davantage aux preuves indirectes. Quelques délégués ont confirmé que leur pays connaissait cette situation. Mais on observe le phénomène inverse : l incidence relativement élevée des «ententes naïves» dans ces pays ententes dans lesquelles les membres ne cherchent pas à dissimuler leur activité, soit parce qu ils ignorent que leur comportement est illégal, soit parce qu ils ne sont pas assez circonspects pour le faire. Dans le cas d ententes naïves, les preuves directes sont relativement nombreuses, ce qui réduit l importance des preuves indirectes. Quelques pays dans lesquels les ententes sont passibles de poursuites pénales en vertu de leur nouvelle législation sur la concurrence ont soulevé un autre point. Il semble que le fardeau de la preuve plus lourd associé aux procédures pénales rende la tâche plus difficile à l autorité de la concurrence. Ces pays préconisent de commencer par engager une procédure administrative, avant de passer ultérieurement à des poursuites pénales le cas échéant. Enfin, les participants à la discussion étaient d accord pour reconnaître qu une culture de la concurrence solide est un composant 15

essentiel de la réussite de tout programme de lutte contre les ententes. L éducation et la sensibilisation du public sont des moyens importants pour forger une telle culture, mais l application rigoureuse de la loi est encore plus efficace. L autorité de la concurrence doit s efforcer d instruire des affaires exemplaires portant sur les ententes dans des secteurs importants, étayées par des preuves convaincantes et démontrant tout l intérêt, pour les consommateurs, d une application efficace de la législation contre les ententes. 16

BACKGROUND NOTE Circumstantial evidence is of no less value than direct evidence for it is the general rule that the law makes no distinction between direct and circumstantial evidence but simply requires that before convicting a defendant the jury must be satisfied of the defendant's guilt beyond a reasonable doubt from all of the evidence in the case. * * * In order to prove the conspiracy, it is not necessary for the government to present proof of verbal or written agreements. Very often in cases like this, such evidence is not available. You may find that the required agreement or conspiracy existed from the course of dealing between or among the individuals through the words they exchanged or from their acts alone. The above quotations, taken from the jury instructions in the recent successful criminal prosecution of the Chairman of the Sotheby s auction house, 1 illustrates that cartel conspirators can be prosecuted, even against the highest standards of proof, without direct evidence of the agreement or of their involvement in it. Indirect (circumstantial) evidence is used in most jurisdictions including those with the longest and most successful records of cartel prosecutions, where competition law enforcers now enjoy the virtuous circle of strong sanctions in past cases energising leniency programs, which generate direct evidence in new cases, and more strong sanctions. 2 Indirect evidence is particularly important for competition law enforcers in jurisdictions without such enforcement records, given that cartel conspiracies are cloaked in secrecy and direct evidence is not forthcoming. The focus of this paper is on the use of indirect evidence in cartel investigations, typically triggered by an episode of suspicious parallel pricing or other behaviour that is not readily explained by usual market forces. When the competition agency suspects that the conduct is the result of an agreement but cannot discover direct evidence to prove the existence of an agreement, what amount and quality of circumstantial evidence is sufficient for this purpose? The key points for the reader to take from the paper are: The provisions of competition laws prohibiting anticompetitive agreements apply not only to explicit agreements but also to other types of joint arrangements, variously identified as arrangements, combinations or concerted practices. In all cases, however, liability for a competition law violation can be imposed only if it can be shown that the parties reached some "conscious commitment to a common scheme. 1 2 Available on the web site of the American Bar Association, at: http://www.abanet.org/antitrust/committees/criminal/taubman.doc. It should be noted that the United States, well along on the virtuous circle, would not normally bring a criminal cartel case on indirect evidence alone. Even in the Sotheby s case, there was direct evidence of the agreement, and there was some direct evidence linking Sotheby s Chairman to it. Much of the evidence against him, however, was circumstantial. 17

Cartels pose a special problem for enforcers because they operate in secret, and their members usually do not co-operate with investigations of their conduct. In experienced jurisdictions, competition authorities in most cases use direct evidence to prove an unlawful conspiracy. It can be difficult to obtain direct evidence of a cartel agreement, however. Enforcers may be faced with the task of proving the existence of a cartel agreement without the benefit of direct evidence. Circumstantial evidence can come in several forms, including evidence of communications between rivals and economic evidence. Economic evidence consists of firm conduct, market structure, and evidence of facilitating practices. All types of evidence can be useful in a case and they should be employed together. Economic theories of oligopoly provide several valuable insights for competition law enforcers: They show that acts consistent with unilateral incentives can lead to a different outcome than when firms act collectively, and that oligopoly does not inevitably lead to cooperation and collective action to increase prices. As a result, enforcers and decision makers should carefully examine whether firm conduct can be described as actions in unilateral self-interest absent an agreement to act jointly, or as actions in the collective interest of all competitors. Conduct consistent with unilateral self interest does not constitute good evidence in a circumstantial cartel case. Consistent with economic theory, a long line of case law has recognised that evidence of parallel conduct, such as simultaneous price increases by rivals, alone is not sufficient proof of a cartel agreement. There must be additional evidence, which tends to prove the existence of an unlawful agreement as required under the applicable standards of proof. Courts sometimes refer to this additional evidence as plus factors. An important type of plus factor is evidence showing that there were communications among the suspected cartel operators in the course of which they could have reached agreement. Economic evidence is another important class of circumstantial evidence. It includes evidence both of conduct by market participants suggesting that they are acting jointly and of market structure that lends itself to collusive activity. One method of analysing economic conduct evidence is to consider whether the conduct would have been in the self interest of the actors if they had not been acting jointly. Circumstantial evidence should be considered in a holistic fashion. The decision maker should assess the cumulative effect of all evidence, rather than require that each item unequivocally support the hypothesis of agreement. Countries differ in the way that they develop evidence in cartel cases. Several factors contribute to these differences, including whether cartels are prosecuted administratively, civilly or criminally; and whether a country has been prosecuting cartels for a long time or has begun an anti-cartel programme only recently. There is a trend in OECD countries toward building cases based on direct evidence. But countries continue to bring cases employing mostly circumstantial evidence where it is appropriate. It is likely that countries just beginning an anti-cartel programme will have some difficulty generating direct evidence, and hence will have to rely more on circumstantial evidence in early cases. While these cases can be difficult, it is important that the new agency establish credibility for its competition law and for its anti-cartel effort. 18

1. Cartel agreements All competition laws prohibit, among other things, anticompetitive conduct by two or more parties acting jointly. Competition laws are written broadly to apply to all forms of agreements, formal and informal, explicit and implicit. Thus, for example, the United States Sherman act applies to any contract, combination... or conspiracy; 3 Article 81(1) of the EC Treaty applies to agreements between undertakings, decisions by associations of undertakings, and concerted practices; Mexico s competition law applies to contracts, agreements, arrangements, or combinations; 4 Chinese Taipei s competition law applies to concerted actions, which is defined as including any contract, agreement or any other form of mutual understanding; 5 and Tanzania s law applies to any agreement, arrangement or understanding between two or more persons, whether or not it is: (a) formal or in writing; or (b) intended to be enforceable by legal proceedings. 6 As the broad statutory language suggests, unlawful agreements among competitors can take many forms. The most common in the business context is the explicit agreement, in which the parties communicate directly, either orally or in writing, specifying the relevant terms and conditions of their enterprise. But agreements do not have to be formal. They can be reached through informal means of communication, including conversations at an association meeting; public statements by senior officers; price announcements or advertisements; or communications through customers. One US court famously noted: A knowing wink can mean more than words. 7 It is important, however, that in all cases competition laws will impose liability for entering into an unlawful agreement only if firms have consciously acted together, whether through formal or informal means of communication. To prove a competition law violation, it must be shown that there has been a meeting of the minds toward a common goal or result, or, in other words, some "conscious commitment to a common scheme." 8 Conversely, liability cannot be found where firms communicated purely in the form of market place action, or where firms communicated, but did not develop some "conscious commitment to a common scheme." 9 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Sherman Act 1. Article 9. Articles 7 and 14. Articles 2 and 8. Esco Corp. v. United States, 340 F.2d 1000, 1007 (9th Cir. 1965). The reader should be careful, though, and not put too much emphasis on these definitions. As other observers have noted, trying to come up with common definitions of "agreement" is not a useful exercise in cases where circumstantial evidence is used to identify a cartel. It is better to describe agreement in terms of what courts in circumstantial evidence cases actually require in terms of firm behaviour that supports the inference of agreement. See, e.g., Jonathan B. Baker, Identifying Horizontal Price Fixing in the Electronic Market Place, 65 Antitrust L. J. 41 (1996) (arguing that this approach emphasizes the (forbidden) process of reaching supracompetitive market outcomes, rather than the outcome itself, which in turn ensures that remedies focus on forbidden acts that can be enjoined.). In a recent article Greg Werden notes the confusion in terminology that is employed in this field. The terms express, explicit, tacit and co-ordinated are often found, but users do not always ascribe the same meaning to them. For example, the term "tacit collusion" has been used to describe an alleged cartel agreement for which only indirect evidence is available, but also to describe cases of parallel, interdependent conduct that does not amount to an unlawful conspiracy. Werden uses the term "spoken agreement" to refer to an unlawful conspiracy. Gregory J. Werden, Economic Evidence on the Existence of 19